Notice: This is the official website of the All Empires History Community (Reg. 10 Feb 2002)

  FAQ FAQ  Forum Search   Register Register  Login Login

[Article] - Athens and Empire c.479-446 BC

 Post Reply Post Reply
Author
Aster Thrax Eupator View Drop Down
Suspended
Suspended

Suspended

Joined: 18-Jul-2006
Online Status: Offline
Posts: 1929
  Quote Aster Thrax Eupator Quote  Post ReplyReply Direct Link To This Post Topic: [Article] - Athens and Empire c.479-446 BC
    Posted: 15-May-2009 at 15:48

Okay, here is the article that's kept me away from all empires - partially - for so long. I initially wanted to do something on the Neo-Assyrians or the Diadochi, but I felt that I should probably concentrate on an area with more sources for starters. Also, this period is one of the core areas of ancient history and is often a core module at unversity, as well as just damn fascinating in its own right! It helped my research and essay skills no end, not to mention my knowledge of the period, and I'm certainly going to do several more essays over the Summer for AE with these new skills! In any case, doing this was - not exaggeration intended - one of the most worthwhile things that I've ever done!

"Athens and Empire - to what extent was Athens between c.479-446 BC an Imperialist power?"
By Sam Edwards/Aster Thrax Eupator

       I.            Introduction

 The legacy of high classical Greece, for all its cultural and intellectual significance, concealed a politically troubled people which, by the end of the 5th century BC were to become embroiled in one of the most brutal and extensive conflicts the ancient world had yet seen. The Peloponnesian war of 431 - 404 in many respects was the logical culmination of two peoples, holding immense political and military power, but were almost diametrically opposed societies with radically differing cultural views. The "cold war" of the c5th century BC between Athens and Sparta and their respective leagues is eerily reminiscent of the period before the first world war and of the early cold war, and is more relevant than ever in that it provides perhaps one of the earliest case-studies ever of the growth and mentality behind imperialist and expansionist states. Despite the inherent complexity of the question addressed – “to what extent was Athens imperialistic?” there is no doubt that between them, the two power-blocs of the Delian and Peloponnesian leagues show a striking continuity in the way which the empires rise, and the rhetoric that is utilised in their construction. However, it must be stressed that even the term “Peloponnesian war” was essentially a synthesis of two wars in the historiography of Thucydides, and thus, the idea of this period as one cohesive conflict is merely retrospective. The imperial legacy of Athens, especially, is historically and archeologically rich; the effects of which are directly evident in the architecture of most modern European cities. To understand the cultural, intellectual and political legacy of Athens, one must first understand her essentially expansionist role in the world of 5th century Greece

    II.            Athenian military imperialism

 In 1832, Clausewitz stated that “…war is not merely a political act, but also a political instrument”[1], and history has proven this maxim to be true and especially relevant to this period.  As Shipley reports, “…war is often said to have been central to Greek society”[2], which can be seen as early as Homer. Empires are perhaps built by war; and Athen’s was foreshadowed by one of the most famous. The Persian wars (c.499-479) unified Greece against the Archenemid enemy. However, this idea of Greece being unified against a Persian enemy has been largely proven to be due to Herodotos’ idealistic depiction of the situation – historians such as Cartledge, emphasise that Herodotos was a “man of the east”, and would have thus, because of the Persian occupation of Ionia, would have been more likely to see the Hellenic league as being beneficial in Ionic terms, rather than to sow the seeds of later discontent. Historiographically, this “east-versus west” thesis can be seen in popular works such as Tom Holland’s “Persian Fire”, which is subtitled “…the battle for the west” – in the light of popular research, therefore, one should not look at Greece politically in the Persian wars in this essentially neo-classist view – she was clearly not unified even at the time of the Persian wars[3]. There is a myriad of evidence to reject this traditional interpretation, and the seeds of discontent can be seen in the 481 meeting of the “Hellenic league”, which Buckley states that it resolved all feuds “…between member states should come to an end”[4], but that “…the command of both of the army and navy should be conferred on the Spartans”[5]. Athens contradicted this by its construction of its fleet, which, by the calculations of Connolly (deduced from both Herodotus and Aeschylus) numbered 380-310 ships[6]. The end manifestation of this “imperialism” was seen in the Peloponnesian war (431-404) which - Thucydides reports - was instigated by “…the growth of Athenian power and the fear which this caused in Sparta”[7]. Between the Persian and the Peloponnesian wars is the “Pentecontaetia” of Thucydides, which is a period ample in examples with which to examine the supposed military “imperialism” of Athens.

The transition from league to empire was slow and arose from military actions against Persia. The Athenian statesman and ardent traditionalist Kimon returned from Thrace to attack the Persian-held Eïon (477). Meiggs considers this suspicious, because “…Athens captured and occupied a strong coast-fortress…rich in timber and silver”[8]. However, Plutarch states that the Persians at Eïon had been “Harassing the Greeks in the neighbourhood”[9]. It is unlikely that these early actions were imperialistic, especially taking into account Meier’s belief that in this period “There is no indication that, apart from Sparta and Argos, any of the prominent cities…were involved in major wars or expansionist policies except in their own vicinities”[10]. The only references to an Athenian “empire” come later, from the c.454 tribute lists.  Thus, Eïon could be seen as a continuation of the Persian war. Later campaigns seem distinctly different – most of them were against Greeks who did not join the Delian league, such as Skyros (473-474), Karystos (472-1), Naxos (469) and Thasos (465-463). Thucydides states that these were because of “…failures to produce the right amount of tribute or the right number of ships”[11]. Meiggs’s statement that “Athens was already forging the fetters with which she would bind her allies”[12]  in retrospect seems valid. Thasos requested Spartan aid, which never came; probably because of an earthquake and the Messenian Helots’ revolt (c.465-461). Rhodes maintains that this occurred because “Athens and Sparta had not yet quarrelled”[13], perhaps showing that Greeks saw a division between the Peloponnesians and Athenians this early. However, early Athenian campaigns were not all against Greeks; for example, the battle of the Eurymedon river (466), which Meiggs called “…the most brilliant success of Kimon’s life”[14], where he gained control of Lycia from the Persians. However, such a battle, that “…probably marked the end of the Persian satrapy which Darius had formed in 513”[15], would surely mean that the requirement for the Delian league was over? Overall, however, we can conclude that between 479 – 469, Athens was not imperialistic, but the conditions for it were clearly created by Kimon under the guise of a new Hellenic impetus to unify against the Archenemid Persian threat.

After 462, the campaigns changed; mainly because of the rise of the new “imperialist” politicians in Athens. After Kimon’s offer to aid the Spartans in their helot revolt in c.462 was rejected, Athens, disgraced, ostracised Kimon and thus, his pan-Hellenism. This resulted in what Croix called the “first Peloponnesian war” (although Souza maintains; “to some extent it lacked the continuity and coherence which is characteristic of a single war”[16]). It may be hard today to see why Athens reacted so scornfully to an insult, but Kagan reminds us that in ancient warfare, “The real motives were often psychological…rather…than practical; that is, they derived from questions of honour and prestige”[17], whilst Croix states that the insult was “…unparalleled…in the whole of Greek history”[18]. Athens, contradicting the conditions of the Delian league, was fortified in c.459, which is clearly indicative of these changing policies. Croix gives us three reasons why the war occurred. Firstly, the Athenian alliance with Argos and Thessaly, against whom Sparta fought several battles; at Tegea (473), Dipaea (471), and Tiryns (468-7). So naturally, Athen’s alliance with Argos in 462 was a threat. Souza further emphasises the “imperialist” results of this, as it gave Athens access to excellent cavalry[19]. Secondly, the occupation of Naupactos by Athens and Messenian Helots (462-459) dominated Peloponnesian commerce, and between 453-446, surrounding Achean states were pressed into the Delian league. Thirdly, there was the Athenian alliance with Megara, which gave access to both the Corinthian and Saronic gulfs by its ports Pegae and Nisaea. Thucydides states that this was why “…Corinth began to conceive such a bitter hatred for Athens”[20], and Kagan believes that this was inevitable: “An alliance with Megara, therefore, would promise Athens enormous advantages, but would also bring Corinth and probably with Sparta the entire Peloponnesian league as well”[21], and Corinth’s anger certainly reinforces this. Meiggs believes that Sparta “…was soon compelled to fight for her position within the Peloponnese”[22], showing a conscious Athenian move against the Peloponnesians. However, Powell tabulates the Athenian with the Spartan campaigns, creating “the theory of Spartan opportunism” – for almost all Athenian campaigns between 465-411, there is a Spartan counterpart[23], and Powell emphasises that Athenian operations in the Aegean clearly threatened Persia and were therefore not imperial actions. Moreover, Didodorus Siculus recounts[24] that by 475-4, Sparta considered taking command of the Persian offensive from Athens by force – which again can be seen to reinforce the idea that Athenian military “imperialism” – even against the Spartans – was reactionary, and this can be used as evidence to suggest the existence of a “war party” in Sparta as early as the 470s.  However, Powell’s judgement[25] relies mainly on examples from after 446. Soon, war commenced with Corinth, who saw the control of Megara and Naupactos by Athens as intolerable, causing several battles – Halieis, Cecryphalea and Megara between 459-458. Athens moved to control the Saronic gulf, and forced Aegina to join the Delian league in 457-6. However, the old anti-Persian campaign continued, and Kimon continued to fight Persia by aiding the rebel Inaros in Egypt (c.459-454). Thus, there was clearly a change in warfare from the rise to power of Perikles in 462, who Plutarch states decided that “…to hold the Spartans in check was one of the prime objectives…and set out to oppose them in every way”[26]. To conclude, it would seem that after 462 we see a clear approach to “imperial” campaigns, but when we consider Kimon’s continuation of the Persian war, the author considers the “middle view” advocated by Hammond, who talks of “…Athens’ offensives on two fronts”[27], to have the most merit.

War was declared in 460-457, manifested in the battles of Tanagra and Oenophyta (457). Sparta reacted by aiding  Boeotia; opening another front. In retaliation Tolmides lead a fleet to burn the Spartan dockyards at Gytheum in 456. Although Meiggs states that Athens was exhausted[28], she had the confidence to pursue a “land empire”; perhaps because the defection of Megara. The defeat of the Egyptian expedition in c.454 made the Athenians reconsider their approach, leading to the five years truce – and Sparta’s peace with Argos – in 451. Kimon’s return reinvigorated the offensive against Persia, such as the Cyprian expedition (c.450), which was so successful that in 449, peace  was made with Persia. Powell states that “the…basis of the league was being removed”[29]; and therefore that Athens could not masquerade her conquests as being for the Delian league. Croix maintains that Athens could have argued that the next Persian king could have broken the peace, so that the continuation of tribute was necessary[30]; thus tribute after 449 would not be imperialistic. However, with this peace much of Athens’ Boeotian conquests were abandoned, and Tolmides’ attempts to regain them resulted in his defeat at the battle of Koroneia (447). Megara rejoined Sparta, allowing the Spartan king Pleistoanax to besiege Athens. Consequently, Perikles agreed to the 30 years’ peace (446), which, according to Hornblower, was Athens’ triumph because it “recognised the existence of the Athenian naval empire”[31]. In conclusion, we can see an almost chronological increase in Athenian imperialism from 479-446, and it is the period between 462-446 that obviously heralded the most extreme and adventurous Athenian campaigns. In military terms, Athens was now clearly an empire.

In conclusion, Athen’s military imperialism can be divided into three main stages – the first period under Kimon immediately after the Persian wars, that may been seen as a continuation of the Persian offensive; the second, after Kimon’s ostracism in 462, in which, although we see Perikles’ imperial ambitions manifested, efforts against Persia are still being pursued; and the first Peloponnesian war, in which military action, as a political “instrument”, to quote Clausewitz[32], is now utilised almost exclusively for Athenian Imperialistic purposes

 III.            Imperial economics

Any attempt to integrate the essentially modern concept of economy into that of Ancient history will be problematic. The dominating theorem of modern scholarship, as emphasised by the “Columbia school”, is that of “substantivism” in this context, that Ancient economics was merely an extension of social status and class rather than a sphere in its own right – in Weber’s words, the ancient man was a “homo politicus”[33], who merely pursued economics as a medium through which to exercise political power – the behaviour of the “Homeric Hero” in some respects can be seen to typify this obsession with status, rather than safety, which in many respects can be seen still reflected in recklessness of economic ventures in this period –  almost all of which were exclusively geared for war. A very basic piece of evidence to emphasise this point is the fact that Aristotle, who intended to catalogue and write about all areas of “episteme” or the Greek divisions of knowledge, does not include “Oikonomikos” (economics) as a separate work, but includes what we would consider to be “economics” in his “politics”. However, although one must maintain scepticism when working with the ancient economy, especially when regarding the lack of sources (there are merely four in-depth major references and explorations of land ownership in Greek primary sources spread over the classical period) and the work of the Columbia school and Finley, a traditional approach, as seen below, shall also be attempted. The best way to simply summarise Athenian economic attitudes between c.479-404 without the influence of the Columbia school would thus be that “A polity’s will for power beyond its borders grows relative to its appetite for foreign resources”[34] – despite the fact that what we regard as “economics” was only really born with Alfred Marshall’s “Principles of economics” in 1890, the concept of ancient economics should still not be ignored, especially for this thesis. The extensive military operations that characterised 5th century Athens must have required a strong economic basis, despite the consensus of historians such as Buckley, that “the basis of Athenian imperial power was its fleet”[35]. However, we must take into account that Greek cities were also essentially autocratic – despite the extensive trade links with eastern Greece, Phoenicia and Egypt that clearly existed from as early as the Mycenaean period, we cannot consider trade to be a basis for such economies. Furthermore, Zimmern  states that “…a bad system of coinage made foreign trade almost impossible”[36]; and thus any Greek state with a reputable currency could have dominated over time, as Athens did. Kagan emphasises the importance of Athen’s location in relation to her imperialism – “…its area of about a thousand square miles is mountainous…and unavailable for cultivation, early Attica was relatively poor”[37]. How, from a “relatively poor”[38] city, Athens was by the 5th century to become (as Rhodes says) “…not merely the most prosperous Greek city but one whose prosperity took a form which made it…supplied with ready money”[39]?

Although the main method of Athenian expansion was military force, others were explored. In 482, Themistokles persuaded the Ekklesia to use the revenue from Laurium Silver mines to construct a navy. When Meiggs states that Themistokles “…contributed more than any other single man to the making of Athens into a great state”[40], he is referring to the construction of the naval ports of the Piraeus rather than the walls of Athens. The fleet was immediately put to “imperial” use – Plutarch states that Themistokles “…incurred the hatred of the allies by sailing round the islands…trying to extort money from them”[41]. Plutarch continues – “In the first place he [Themistokles] was the only man who had the courage to come before the people and propose that the revenue from the silver mines at Laurium…be set aside and the money used to built triremes”[42], implying that there was a latent support for such policies. Zimmern gives a fascinating socio-economic explanation for this, stating; “It was by free gifts that the Athenians armed the fleets which were so supreme on the seas”[43], in which he refers to the cultural generosity of the Greeks, or “Xenia”. Zimmern also emphasises that this is why what he calls “municipal socialism”[44]was never occurred, because of the “dislike…for discipline and organisation”[45], which, although questionable, would explain why Athenian imperialism was individualistic – it was not a faceless venture by a nation-state; it could not be in such a small community. Indeed, many citizens were expected to “patron” a vessel, and were known as “Trierarchs”, which reflects this obligation – this kind of support for the mobilisation and arming of the fleet was primarily done via the medium of the pseudo-religious “Leutourgia”; a religious element can thus be strongly detected (is it any coincidence that the Delian league treasury was moved to the Acropolis and the “adyton” or second chamber of the Parthenon?), granting yet more kudos to the now orthodox “substantivist” argument upheld by Finley. Thus, many of the reasons behind the creation of the economic background for the large military ventures of the c5th century in Athens may be seen as a mere reflection of the militaristic culture and associated honour that would come from such an act – not the economic ramifications of it, as Finley states, the “…institution of wage-labour is a sophisticated late comer”[46], and thus the loyalty of Athen’s men-at-arms was not essentially economic, but moral and cultural – arguably more virulent encouraging factors. However, from a more abstract standpoint, the reputation of Athenian coinage meant that some states, such as Aegina from c480 may have used Athenian currency voluntarily – Finley argues against any such point (admittedly, evidence for the c480 coinage act is fragmentary, and so we must understand the difficulties that Finley faces) on the basis that, if it was conceived to give Athenian merchants advantages over their clients, the act would have provided benefits for all – even subject states – within the Athenian empire, and so the decree must be regarded as a means of political control[47]. However, if this was the case, why, as stated above, did foreign states outside of Athenian control decide to use it? The answer can only logically be in an appreciation of the silver standard of Athenian coinage – coinage was not, as Finley maintains, utterly irrelevant in the ancient world; why in that case would Sparta have preferred using the Persian Gold Daric, with all of the resources of the treasury at Persepolis to increase its value, if coinage was irrelevant to the workings of the ancient economy? Thus, the removal of any economic basis for imperialistic ventures seems admittedly to be an extreme position. Furthermore, as we see in the rebellions of Skyros (473-474), Karystos (472-1) and Naxos (469), Athens would not allow member states to leave the Delian league; possibly because of the real value that the leagues’ treasury gave to Athenian coin. This can be seen in the rebellion of the Thasians (465-463), whose gold mines were used by Athens. At the same time, Athens also founded a Thracian colony – later called Amphipolis – on a major trade location. We can argue against overt “imperial” decisions, however – Zimmern’s statement that a “fiercely isolationalist” [48] Greek state must “…feed and clothe itself in its own way”[49] surfaces when we consider that Athens was unable to do this, so to some extent her “empire” (grain was imported from Egypt and the Black sea (c.459-404)) may have been inevitable. Cook emphasises the isolation of Greece – “For ordinary loans and rents 12 per cent a year was normal, with interest paid monthly. Maritime rates were 33 1/3 per cent for four months to compensate for…shipwreck…”[50], obviously, in such a distrustful economic climate, Athens would have to stimulate confidence through force. Thus, economic imperialism seems limited in this period. It would seem that long-term socio-economic conditions from c.600-479 sowed the seeds for events in c.479-446. Thus, Hammond’s view, that “by the middle of the century Athens was winning a place…in the expanding world of Greek commerce”[51] thus seems plausible, but through necessity. Although one can argue against many of these economic interpretations via the “substantivist” position of Finley, the fact remains that there are many campaigns throughout the c.460s especially that clearly show an overt interest in the ramifications of Athenian imperialism on her economics, and something of this kind must have been on Kimon’s agenda in this period.

In this period, Periklean economics are perhaps the most famous. After the failure of the Egyptian expedition (459-454), the treasury of the Delian league was moved from Delos to Athens, possibly from a renewed fear of the Persians. Soon after the battle of Eurymedon (c.469) Delian league members changed their tribute from ships to gold – in many respects, this may have given the Athenians the pretext to transfer the treasury to Athens (454), but interestingly, this is not mentioned by Thucydides, who may not have regarded it as provocative. Scholars are unsure if this was an “Imperial” move by Athens, but the sixteenth tribute to Athens and projects such as the Parthenon (c.447-432/1) can be considered evidence enough. The Parthenon especially is testament to the economic legacy of Athens in this period – unlike contempary Doric temples, all ninety-two metopes were carved – an amazing architectural feat which could not have been achieved were it not for the “…immense financial backing available” [52], in the words of B.F. Cooke. Furthermore, the draconian measures taken by Perikles in the creation of the Athenian imperial fleet cannot have been even conceived without a conscious appreciation that Athens alone could not afford the financial burden, and Jones gives us just a sample of the immense cost of imperialism – “Perikles is stated to have kept sixty triremes in commission for eight months in the year and he maintained a fleet of 300 in the dockyards. The dockyards must have given employment to an army of craftsmen, as well as to 500 guards, and the crews of the cruising triremes would have numbered 12’000 men, paid a drachma a day"[53]The contempary response can be seen from Plutarch - some Athenians complained “we are gilding and beautifying our city…with costly stones and statues and temples worth millions of money”[54], to which Perikles’ response was the Athenians had “…every right to use the surplus income”[55]. The Athenians organised this new tribute system with a care that could only be instigated by a realisation of their economic power. Control mechanisms of empire are clearly in place, as seen on the tribute lists*, where we find the cities of the league arranged in five provinces (Caria, Ionia, Thrace, Hellespont and the islands), committees created – “Logistae”, “Hellenotamiae” – to audit tribute, and the “Phrounarch” – a tribute official (who soon disappears from Athenian tribute lists around c.460-459). Much of this information comes from a decree from Ephyre, (c.453-2), which Rhodes states “…In a strict sense could be represented as a colony of Athens"[57], who reinforces this by evidence from Plutarch: “…a council of 120…to be established by…Athenian overseers and a…garrison commander”[58], and additionally, the provision of Athenian magistrates, who in the case of Chalkis’ revolt (446-445), were able to help regain control through lawsuits. Also important were the “Kleuarchies” or colonists, who dominated the local economies, and were sent out in relatively large numbers – “1000 settlers to the Chersonese, 1000 to Thrace…”[59].  These colonists were undoubtedly of importance – the much later play by Aristophanes, “Wasps”, mentions garrison duty in Byzantium[60] – it is hardly coincidental that Byzantium was a major city on the Hellespont, through which Athens gained much of her corn supplies until c.404. We see some of the military actions of this period – such as the presence of a fleet near Pegae in 458/7 – to have economic consequences – as Croix states, “The Nisaea-Megara-Pegae route may perhaps have been used sometimes by merchants trading between Athens and the West if and when the way cross the Isthmus of Corinth was closed to them”[61]. In this case, we could also view the 462 alliance with Megara and Argos as an Athenian action to secure their economic gains. Athens had already dominated the Peloponnesian (more specifically, Corinthian) pottery trade in the c.7-6th centuries, as can be seen by the dominance of Athenian black-figure ware in the 6th century. However, Croix cites Cook’s warning “…against overestimating the value of trade in painted pottery and its importance in the economic life in any Greek city”[62]. However, one can dispute with both Cook and Croix when one considers that the artistic – and thus commercial – legacy of Athens had reached Italy as early as the c.530s. Athens had a long history of attempting to dominate traditionally Peloponnesian trading routes; the foundation of Thurii by Athens in Italy (c.446/443) and her treaty with the Sicilian cities (c.443) dominated the grain routes from Sicily and indeed, the initial causes of the Peloponnesian war – the Megaran decree and the Corcyran alliance (433-432) – were both fundamentally concerned with trade. However, de Croix argues against the latter point[63], but this has been considered wildly revisionist[64] and as can be seen above, there is an overwhelming amount of evidence to suggest the commercial/economic reading of these events. Current scholarly consensus can be summarised by Antonaccio, who states that “…the Greek experience of colonisation cannot be said to have participated in the kind of imperialism that operated in other times and places…Greek colonies were not put in place to claim territory…or to secure resources to the state, or with any of the other justifications of imperial expansion in history”[65] – although there was clearly a strong ethnic relationship between the colonists and their “Metropoleis” or “mother-city”, most colonies soon developed into a cultural mix, and in many respects became utterly independent, as can be seen by the revolt of Epidamnos from Corinth (c.433 BC). Athens was no different in following the trend of colonisation in the Archaic period – Osborne calculates that in the last generation of the 8th century BC, a new colony was being founded in Italy or Sicily by Greeks every two years[66]. Athenian economic “Imperialism” can thus be considered non-existent in the archaic period, and thus, Periklean economically interventionist policy in the mid 5th century BC cannot be considered to rely on firm foundations of Athens as an economically imperialist power – such tactics, if they consciously existed at all, were the product of a new approach towards executing and interventionalist policy. Some of the best evidence relies on the fact that by 449, the peace of Kallias – the evidence for which is disputed, however - removed any reason for the Delian league to exist in an economic, military or political form. How this affected Athens is not clear, but Rhodes calculates from the tribute lists there was one year – 449/8 – where tribute was negligible, and two others – 448/7, 447/6 – where tribute was resisted[67], showing that, perhaps, contemparies clearly did see the peace of Kallias as a cue for resistance; the chronology seems to point to some kind of boycott of the league as a political measure. Essentially, with such evidence, it is hard to see how the Athenian “vassals” could not have seen the 454 movement of the treasury as a bid for imperial power. Furthermore, by 446/5, all allegiance on the tribute lists is dedicated towards the people of Athens; Athens has now overtly admitted that the “members” of the Delian league are vassals of Athens – the transformation from league to empire, on an economic basis, is now obvious – Meiggs’s statement that “…there was a general tendency towards closer control”[68] seems an understatement to say the least.

In conclusion, Athenian economic imperialism seems to have been a method of enforcement for the her empire, but the issue appears to be to what extent it was a conscious one. One could easily say that Athens must have realised its economic programme was imperialistic when we regard that throughout the whole of this period, landowning was “the only form of reliable, long-term investment in Greco-Roman antiquity”[69]. Thus, in using the Delian league to gain that land, and thus economic security, she was carrying out an imperialist policy, but one could easily discount this by regarding that the Peloponnesian league was Bi-Cameral – Sparta thus held a great amount of land and thus, initially, potential economic power to rival that of Athens. Attica, a comparatively barren landscape to the Peloponnese, would have forced Athens to resort to her only alternative – to combat Sparta in a potential economic cold war using the Delian league to do battle. In any case, Athen’s economic policy was clearly reactive, and whatever lands she did possess in Attica were consistently threatened by siege in the first Peloponnesian war.  Although initially Athen’s economic policy cannot be considered a conscious act of imperialism, the sources show that in retrospect, it was an aggravating factor for the later Peloponnesian war (431-404), and towards the latter decades of the 5th century, Athens displays a clear understanding of her economic prowess – to such an extent that many historians regard trade to be a decisive factor in the outbreak of that later conflict. Overall, evidence seems to be conflicting and vague, but although simplistic imperialism based on the domination of trade routes and acquisition of gold and silver are plausible, but we must regard Athenian economic imperialism to be at first circumstantial and wholly reactionary, and not psychologically motivated by imperialism, but by the “Columbian” school’s Homeric warrior-status basis. Admittedly, some of the chronological evidence by the mid 5th century as postulated by Rhodes around the time of the movement of the Delian treasury to Athens (454) and the peace of Kallias (c.449) does cater towards the idea of conscious Athenian economic dominance. However, this interpolation in regards to the tribute lists is fundamentally flawed methodology – the tribute lists and the peace of Kallias are essentially manifestations of political and not economic imperialism, and thus we return to the “status mentality” principle of Finley and the Columbian school – Athens was, to conclude, clearly not consciously performing what would now be considered “economic warfare”.

 
...Continued in a post below
Back to Top
Aster Thrax Eupator View Drop Down
Suspended
Suspended

Suspended

Joined: 18-Jul-2006
Online Status: Offline
Posts: 1929
  Quote Aster Thrax Eupator Quote  Post ReplyReply Direct Link To This Post Posted: 15-May-2009 at 15:49
...And more
 
 
 IV.            The struggle of factions
 
Almost a century after the first Athenian empire, Aristotle stated that “man is by nature a political animal”[70],  and the essence of whether Athens was an “imperialist” city-state in this period or not must be examined primarily from a political basis – the military and economic actions of Athens in this period will only be a manifestation of her internal political climate. As a rule, Greek political factions in this period offered two alternatives – a co-operation with the “outside” against Persia, or a strongly xenophobic and isolationist element, which appears to have been the norm. However, although this may seem so foreign to us, the principle of “national security” and the “us-them” mentality permeates throughout the ages – much the same sort of political division can be seen between the division of opinion against and for the war and terror, and before, the cold war. The Athenian boulterion was, as national assemblies are today, in many respects a battlefield between these two conflicting nationalist ideologies.  In the midst of this, we must be thankful to have a historian in Thucydides whose “uncompromising realism”[71] lead Croix to compare him to figures such as Machiavelli or Hobbes, who both had, in retrospect, incredibly incisive observations of their historical periods.
 
The ambitious foreign and economic policy of Athens in the period 469-446 was naturally mirrored by dramatic changes in the political climate within the city itself. From a background of vigorous tyrannical rulers such as Cylon (c.630), Draco (c.620), Pisistratus (c.550s-530s), Hippias and Hipparchus (c.530-511) and Isagoras (c.508) Athenian democracy gradually began to take hold – the conditions for which were created in the reigns of Solon (c.594) and Cleisthenes (c.509). However, Athenian democracy was greatly distrusted by much of Greece, and many of the exiled tyrannical families such as the Alcmaeonidae encouraged Clemenes I of Sparta to invade in 510. The legacy of Athenian politics is thus dominated by this background of tyrannical rulers and foreign intervention; the latter in this context is especially important – Croix maintains that any military intervention after this point must have “seemed to the bulk of the Athenians to be aggressive attempts to gain control over their internal affairs”[72]. Thus, it is of no surprise that the first political “party” to exercise control over Athens was the “hawks” of Themistokles, which from 479 onwards exercised a vigorously anti-Spartan foreign policy – the later “party” – the “Doves” of Kimon – with their pro-Delian league, Anti-Persian foreign policy must have seemed incisive – and radical – for the time. In some respects, the two “parties” juxtapose the ideologies of the other – Perikles – a staunch “hawk” – is made to say by Thucydides that Athen’s empire is now “like a tyranny”[73], and  even via the sympathetic Thucydides – a Periklean “hawk”, we see that, despite their rhetoric, the “hawks” offered a return to what would have been seen as a tyrannical government across Athenian-held states. Therefore, it is these two “Parties” that will be the key players of Athenian politics in the high classical period in Athens.
 
As stated above, there were two main “parties” available in regards to foreign policy to Athens in this period – socio-economically, they were also divided along the lines of tyranny, or democracy – later alternatives were to be oligarchies and aristocracies (with the rise of the “middle” party under Alcibiades after c.421). The “hawks” such as Themistokles and Perikles believed that, in the words of Buckley “…once the Persians had been beaten, and once removed from Greek territory, would no longer offer any serious threat to mainland Greece and Athens. The main danger to Athens in the future would come from Sparta and the Peloponnese”[74]. The mentality behind the “hawks” can be seen as an extension, in many respects, of the xenophobic mentality explained above – although, as the Greeks often claimed “we share the same blood and the same language”[75], there was a distinct division between the Ionian, Dorian and Attic Greek in both culture and religion – the austere oligarchic militarism of Sparta and the cosmopolitan democracy of Athens were thus, with such a mentality, incompatible new power-blocs in the post-Persian Greece. Hall provides a gripping account of how, in many respects, the very ethnic background of the two combatants can be seen reflected throughout Greece[76] – the three early “tribes” of Sparta – the Hiylleis, Dymanes and Pamphyloi; which are present in cities such as Corinth, Sikyon, Kos, Locris and Issa; whereas the presence of Mycenaean Naue II Slashing swords, and similarities in the names of months in Athens, Miletos, Rhodes and Epidaurus all point to a joint Ionian cultural heritage[77]. Clearly, with relatively large cultural differences, epitomised by the two main cities in Greece by the c5th century BC – Athens and Sparta – in such an insular and closed society, prejudice was bound to follow. The tensions between the two ethnic groups are not merely a current abstraction – as early as the dimly-remembered archaic period, in the first sacred war (595-585), the Amphictyonic League of Delphi – comprised mainly of Ionian Greeks – called a curse for the utter destruction of the aggressor, Kirrha; a mainly Doric city. Clearly, therefore, cultural prejudices and awareness were settled deeply into the ancient Greek mind.
 
The fears of the “hawks” were proven to the Athenian citizen when Kimon’s forces were sent home by the Spartans in 462/1 after an offer of help against the Messenian Helot rebels. The Delian league and spirit of Greek co-operation that had prevailed in the 500-480s seemed broken – the martial Greek culture – as exemplified in Homer’s works, would have seen such a response by the Spartans to have been the height of insult, so, as Meyer states, “the proponents of war usually had a good chance of prevailing”[78]. The Athenians, initially breaking the clauses of the Delian league by fortifying their city in c.493/2 and 479, saw Spartan attempts to prevent this as an insult to their freedom. Combined with his victory at Salamis in 480, Themistokles was in an excellent position to rouse Athen’s imperialistic and xenophobic spirit, as emphasised by two phrases from Plutarch – “he told them…that through the strength of their fleet they had not only the power to drive off the barbarians, but also to become the leaders of Greece”[79] and “This made it all the easier for Themistokles to carry his point. There was no need to terrify the Athenians with the threat of Darius and the Persians, who were far away”[80]. Opposition to such martial vigour by the main opponent to Themistokles, Aristides appeared culturally inappropriate by the standards of the time. Moreover, the cosmopolitanism of the “Doves” and thus contact in Athens between foreigners and Athenians, Rhodes argues, “were frequent and causing anxiety in some circles”[81], as can be reinforced by the Athenian supremacist attitudes shown and sometimes parodied in the works of Sophokles and Euripides – the “Hawks” obviously knew and exploited this, as the Athenian citizenship laws of Perikles and Ephilates illustrate. Moreover, the “hawks” could play on the traditionally (rather ironically) Aristocratic status of many of the “Doves” – Plutarch (despite his evident sympathies for the doves) mentions Kimon’s aristocratic connections and even compares him to Croesus[82] – and since aristocrats had traditionally been pro-Spartan and anti-democratic, and had organised the earlier invasion by Cleomenes I of Sparta in 510, it would have been easy for “hawks” to defeat many of them on such grounds. The political vacuum left by Kimon in c.462/1 was easy for men such as Perikles and Ephilates to fill – they instantly began to appeal to the people by disbanding the Areopagus and restricting the laws – a traditionally aristocratic law court – and thus appeal to the people. Moreover, the “hawks” were a group with broad social membership – on the one side, one sees Ephilates – “poor but incorrigible”[83] – whilst on the other, Perikles – a staunch aristocrat. Initially, the victory of Themistokles over Aristides must have looked excellent – the Delian league formed in 481, the victory over Aegina in 480 and the victory at Salamis in the same year. Thus, it is of no surprise that with such excellent conditions to coincide with their ideology, such a faction was to gain support and quite clearly influence Athenian policy.
 
In many respects, the Cleisthannic reforms of 508 had created a “moderate democracy” or “isonomia”, which Kimon and his “dove” faction were attempting to preserve. Themistokles saw that Athen’s future glory would be dependent on the lower classes who rowed the ships, and it is for this reason that he championed the 482 ship building programme. In retrospect, Kimon, who was a “staunch supporter of the aristocratic council, the Areopagus”[84] seems to have been a little short sighted. In many respects, the Cleisthannic reforms of which Kimon and the “dove” faction were strong supporters were to prove their downfall – the principle of “ostracism”, introduced in 487, ironically by Cleisthenes – was used to banish him from Athens in 461. The procedure required a minimum of 6000 votes by Athenian citizens – who were far more likely to be won over by the democratic rhetoric of the “hawks” rather than the “isonomic” rhetoric of the “doves”. In many respects, the political rise of the “doves” mirrors these internal political changes of Athen’s constitution – Plutarch states that Themistokles “…increased the standing of the people at the upper classes’ expense and filled them full of confidence, with power now passing into the hands of sailors, boatswains and pilots”[85], and it is of no coincidence that such a political change advocated by Themistokles happens at almost the same time as the victory at Salamis in 480. In regarding the effectiveness of the political rhetoric of the “doves” throughout their period of primacy in the c.470s-80s Powell reminds us that we must be suspicious of Plutarch, who states that the victory over the Persians at Eurymedon in 466 surpassed those of Marathon (490), Salamis (480) and Plataea (479) and that Kimon’s ostracism was done with little justification[86]. If we take Powell’s criticisms of Kimon and examine, as Thucydides reports, the disastrous effects of the Egyptian expedition in c.459-6[87] and the misguided siege of Thasos in c.465, Kimon’s military brilliance can be brought into question, and thus, such claims may have been easily refuted by the “hawks”. It is intensely ironic that Kimon’s foreign policy lead directly to the introduction of the constitutional changes that he and his faction so despised. In many respects we can see the political failure of the “Doves” in a Marxist manner – Hammond states that at the beginning of the 5th century, “There was as yet little contrast between the hoplites and the thetes in their services to the state…thus both groups gained in self confidence…They worked together to rebuild the fortifications of Attica, and they fought side by side to develop the Athenian alliance…”[88]. However, when we regard the quote of Plutarch above (14.2), we can see that by at least the 470s, the “thetes” or sailor class had risen in power, as the constitutional reforms Perikles and Ephilates show. Tactically, Athens no longer won her victories via the upper-class hoplite, but by the mass populace, rowing in triremes. The Marxist approach could be further reinforced when we consider the anger of a noble of the Eupatridae family – Aeschylos, who makes his character Athena state in “The Eumenides” that “…And while this judgement fills, my city, silence will be best. So that you can learn my everlasting laws. And you too, that our verdict may well be observed by all”[89], which has been taken by Meiggs to reflect the anger of the nobility against the dissolution of the Areopagus, and the insult that this presented to the nobility of Athens[90]. As stated above, Kimon’s successes, ironically, showed to Athens what her naval power was capable of, and thus, he can be considered the father of the “hawk” movement. One can see the success of the “doves” as being overemphasised by historians from the ancient world, and the position of the “doves” in the late-mid 5th century to be, despite Plutarch’s bias, to be weak, offering an easy opponent to the dynamic “hawk” faction.
 
In conclusion, the domestic position of Athenian politicians usually corresponds with their approach to foreign policy. The success of Athenian imperialism was largely to be dependent on the social makeup of Athens in the 5th century. One can see, that with a rapidly changing foreign policy, the relatively old “isonomia” of Cleisthenes was incompatible. The main failure of Kimon rested on the fact that he was attempting to retain an outdated constitution in the face of changing military tactics which would challenge the hoplite-based social structure  makeup which Athens had relied upon to win her battles since the archaic period. Kimon’s attitude towards foreign policy can also be perceived as outdated – when he urged his fellow politicians “not to allow Greece to go lame, nor to allow their city to loose it’s yoke-fellow”[91], he was ignorant of the fact that for a long time, Greece had perceived herself as two different sub-divisions – the Doric and the Ionic; the sacred war of c.448-447 can be used to reinforce this fact, where we see the Peloponnesians and the Delians involved in a cold war to grant control of Delphi for their respective “ethnic” groups. Essentially, however, the brilliance of Periklean rhetoric and anachronisms of Kimon eventually decided the outcome of Athenian foreign policy.
 
    V.            Conclusion
 
In conclusion, we can state that Athens - unbeknownst to her for much of the 5th century – clearly instigated the creation of the “Athenian empire”, and that it was clear recognised by the political establishment of the city as such by c.462 under Perikles. Although socio-economic causes for its creation are, as show above, disparate and difficult to interpret, the cultural reasons behind such a political impetus are easily recognised from their origins in the tyrannies of early Athens, and their association with the Spartan oligarchy. In many respects, when attributing blame for the ultimately devastating result of these events – the Peloponnesian war of 431-404 – we must realise that in the creation of the Delian league, all participants were unaware to a large extent of the opportunity that they had created for a single ambitious state. The silver veins of Laurium and the cultural paranoia of Sparta were easily exploited by a cabal of socially radical and xenophobic politicians whose imperialist aim was clear. From c.462, it was a consciously imperialist mentality in a state that, after a period of intense brutality in the Persian wars, acted as humans naturally do, and utilised her situation in an impressive show of political and diplomatic manoeuvring, the conditions for which were already in place from the Persian invasion. Fundamentally, however, attempting to find a political impetus for Imperialism in a society that was fundamentally a warrior culture is itself an anachronism, which brings forth a great amount of problems; this would be all the more so if we do not see the telling fact that other Greek states in this “warrior culture” felt threatened by the attitude of Athens. However, to apply the “substantivist” view to all these areas of imperialism is essentially going to result in a reduction ad absurdum; one which, more dangerously, relies extrapolation of the “status mentality” – by regarding Homer as a moral and cultural “bible” on which to rest out assumptions on 5th century Athenians (when, in any case, Homer was supposedly a 9-8th century Ionian), is ruinous methodology and we forget that in the minds of the contempories of Anaxagoras and Socrates there rested the potential to understand and comprehend a principle such as “economic imperialism” or “cultural imperialism” – these men were not the products of the Homeric world. However, the economic debates of the last century concerning the ancient economy are a veritable labyrinth of complexity – on the basis military operations and cultural legacy alone, Athens was an obvious imperial power by c.454, and knew it! Thus, if we conclude that Athens was an “Imperialist” power, which seems almost unavoidable – even by the standards of the time – whilst looking at the assembled evidence, her imperialism was merely of a reactionary nature – the Peloponnesian league, and especially Sparta, represented an almost completely contrary cultural and political approach to life; one which the martial philosophy and values of Greece demanded, opposed. Despite the cultural fusion which the Delian league offered and created, Herodotus’ perception of a three-fold division[92] (Dorians, Aeolians and Ionians) in Greece, (recognised, in his account, even by a Persian commander such as Mardonius decades before the 5th century[93]) perhaps provides us with a maxim that history has often proven true – the clash of opposing cultures and subsequent paranoia – which was, perhaps, at the heart of Periklean Athens’ clearly imperialist position throughout the latter half of the 5th century BC. 
 
Back to Top
Aster Thrax Eupator View Drop Down
Suspended
Suspended

Suspended

Joined: 18-Jul-2006
Online Status: Offline
Posts: 1929
  Quote Aster Thrax Eupator Quote  Post ReplyReply Direct Link To This Post Posted: 15-May-2009 at 15:52
...And finally, the bibliography and references - almost there!
 
 
 VI.            Select Bibliography
 
Aeschylos, “The Orestia”, 1979, London, Viking Penguin, trans: Fagles, Robert
Aristophanes, “The eleven comedies”, 1948, New York, Liveright, trans: not named
Aristotle, “The Athenian constitution”, 1984, Middlesex, Penguin, trans: Rhodes, P.J
Aristotle, “The politics”, 1967, Middlesex, Penguin, trans: Sinclair, T.A
Antonaccio, “Colonisation, Greece on the move, 900-480” in “The Cambridge companion to Archaic Greece”, Cambridge, New York, 2007
Boardman, John (edited by, with Griffin, Jasper and Murray, Oswyn), “The oxford history of the classical world”, 1995, Oxford, The Oxford university press
Buckley, Terry, “Aspects of Greek history 750-323 BC”, 1996, London, Routledge
Burn, A.R., “The Pelican history of Greece”, 1966, Middlesex, Pelican/Penguin
Bury, J.R. (with Meiggs, Russell), “A history of Greece”, 1978, Basingstoke, Macmillan
Carr, E.H., “What is history?”, 1961, Middlesex, Pelican/Penguin
Cartledge, Paul, public lecture, “Herodotos and how he won the west”, Hellenic institute, London, 7/4/2009
Clausewitz, Carl Von, “On war”, 1982, London, Penguin, trans: Rapoport, Anatol
Cook, B.F. “The Parthenon Marbles”, the British museum press, London, 2000 (1984)
Connolly, Peter, “Greece and Rome at war”, 2006, London, Greenhill books
De Croix, G.E.M, “The origins of the Peloponnesian war”, 1989, London, Duckworth
Finley, F.I, “The ancient economy”, 1999, University of California press, London
Griffin, Jasper (edited by, with Boardman, John and Murray, Oswyn, “The oxford history of the classical world”, 1995, Oxford, The Oxford university press
Hall. Jonathan M, “Polis, Community and Ethnic identity” in “The Cambridge companion to Archaic Greece”, Cambridge, New York, 2007
Hammond, N.GL., “A history of Greece to 322 BC”, 1979, Oxford, Oxford University Press
Herodotus, “The histories”, 1997, New York, Routledge, trans: George Rawlinson
Jones, A.H.M, “Athenian Democracy”, 1978 (1977), Oxford, Blackwell,
Kagan, Donald, “The Peloponnesian war – Athens and Sparta in savage conflict 431-404 BC”, 2005, London, Harper-Collins
Mackay, Christopher S, “Ancient Rome – a military and political history”, 2007, New York, Cambridge University Press
Meiggs, Russell (with Bury, J.R., “A history of Greece”, 1978, Basingstoke, Macmillan
Meier, Christian, “Athens – a portrait of the city in its golden age”, 1999, London, John Murray
Murray, Oswyn (edited by, with Boardman, John and Griffin, Jasper), “The oxford history of the classical world”, 1995, Oxford, The Oxford university press
Plutarch, “The rise and fall of Athens”, 1966, Middlesex, Penguin, trans: Ian Scott-Kilvert
Powell, Anton, “Athens and Sparta – constructing Greek Political and Social History from 478 B.C.”, 1988, London, Routledge
Rhodes, P.J., “A History of the Classical Greek World 478-323 BC”, 2006, Oxford, Blackwell
Rich, John  (edited by, Shipley, Graham), “War and Society in the Greek world”1995, London, Routledge
Shipley, Graham (edited by, with John Rich), “War and Society in the Greek world”1995, London, Routledge
Swan, Harriet (edited by), “Big questions in history”, 2006, London, Vintage
Thucydides, “A history of the Peloponnesian war”, 1972, London, Penguin, trans: Rex Warner
Zimmern, Alfred, “The Greek Commonwealth”, 1961, London, Oxford University Press
 
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------
[1] Clausewitz, “on war”, 1.24, p119
[2] Shipley, “war and soc. In the G. world”, 1.1, p13
[3] Cartledge, Paul, public lecture, “Herodotos and how he won the west”, Hellenic institute, London, 7/4/2009
[4] Buckley, “Aspects”, p167
[5] Buckley, “Aspects”, p167
[6] Connolly, “Greece and Rome at war”, part 1.9, p25
[7] Thucydides, “Hist.”, 1.23.28-29
[8] Meiggs, “Hist.”, chp. 8.5, p208
[9] Plutarch, “Kimon”, 7.4-5
[10] Meier, “Athens”, chp35, p44
[11] Thucydides, “Hist.”, 1.99.1-3
[12] Meiggs, “Hist.”, chp.8.5, p210
[13] Rhodes, “Hist”, 3.2, p28
[14] Meiggs, “Hist.”, chp. 8.5, p208
[15] Hammond, “Hist”, chp. 5.2 p259
[16] Souza, “Hist”, chp. 1.2, p13
[17] Kagan, “Pelop”, chp.2.1, p27
[18] Croix, “Origins”, chp.5.2, p179
[19] Souza, “Hist”, chp.1.2, p13
[20] Thucydides, “Hist”. 1.103.18-19
[21] Kagan, “Pelop”,chp.1.3, p16
[22] Meiggs, “History”. chp. 8.1. p202
[23] Powell, “Ath.and.Spart.”. chp.4.8, p118-121
[24] Didorus Sicilius, “Library” 11.5, Perseus digital library http://www.perseus.tufts.edu/hopper/
[25] Powell, “Ath.and.Spart.”. chp.4.8, p118-121
[26] Plutarch, “Perikles”, 21.4-6
[27] Hammond, “Hist”, 4.2, p292
[28] Meiggs, “Hist”, 9.3, p222
[29] Powell, “Ath.and.Spart.” chp.2.3 p49
[30] Croix, “Origins” appen.VII, p311
[31] Hornblower, “Hist” (in “Ox. His. Class. Chp.6.1, p124
[32] Clausewitz, “on war”, 1.24, p119
[33] Weber, Karl, citied by Morris, Ian, in Finley, “Ancient economy”, intro. xv
[34] Swan (edit.), “Big questions”, chp. 5 (Drayton), p61
[35] Buckley, “Aspects”, p.286
[36] Zimmern, “Commonwealth”, chp.10, p307
[37] Kagan, “Pelop”,chp.1.2, p7-8
[38] Kagan, “Pelop”,chp.1.2, p7-8
[39] Rhodes, “Hist”, chp.9.2 p94
[40] Meiggs, “Hist”, chp.9.10, p165
[41] Plutarch, “Themistokles.”, 21.1-2
[42] Plutarch, “Themistokles”, 4.1-6
[43] Zimmern, “Commonwealth”, chp.9, p290
[44] Zimmern, “Commonwealth”, chp.10 p294
[45] Zimmern, “Commonwealth”, chp.10 p294
[46] Finley, “Ancient economy”, chp3, p65
[47] Finley, “Ancient economy”, chp7, p168-169
[48] Zimmern, “Commonwealth”, chp.9, p287
[49] Zimmern, “Commonwealth”, chp.9, p287
[50] Cook “Greeks till”, chp.4.6, p130
[51] Hammond, “Hist”. chp.6.9 p166
[52] B.F. Cook, “The Parthenon Marbles”, chp.3, p 22
[53] Jones, A.H.M, “Athenian democracy”, chp.1, p7
[54] Plutarch, “Perikles”, 12.15-18
[55] Buckley, “Aspects”, p33
[57] Rhodes, “Hist”. chp.5.2 p47
[58] Plutarch “Perikles”, 11.30-32
[59] Plutarch “Perikles”, 11.30-32
[60] Buckley, “Aspects”, p288, (Aristophanes “Wasps” lines 235-7 quoted)
[61] Croix, “Origins”. chp.6.2, p215
[62] Croix, “Origins”. chp7 p225-292
[63] Croix, “Origins”. chp7 p225-29
[64] Chester Starr of the “American history review” described Croix’s work to be "superb in its argumentation and wrongheaded in its thrust."
[65] Antonaccio, “Colonisation, Greece on the move, 900-480” in “The Cambridge companion to Archaic Greece” , p 205-6
[66]Osborne, citied in Antonaccio, “Colonisation, Greece on the move, 900-480” in “The Cambridge companion to Archaic Greece” p 54 + table 1 and 2
[67] Rhodes, “Hist”. chp.55.2 p49-50
[68] Meiggs, “Hist”. chp.8.5 p211
[69] Mackay, “Ancient Rome”, chp.7, p97
[70] Aristotle, “Politics”, 1.2.71-72, p28
[71] Croix, “Origins”, chp.1.2, p25
[72] Croix, “Origins”, chp.5.1, p167
[73] Thucydides, “Hist”. 2.63.11
[74] Buckley, “Aspects”, p.213
[75] Meyer, “Athens”, chp.5, p241
[76] Hall, "Polis, Community and Ethnic identity” in “The Cambridge companion to Archaic Greece” chp.2, p 54 + table 1 and 2
[77] Ibid p.57
[78] Meyer, “Athens”, chp.5, p239
[79] Plutarch, “Themistokles”, 4.20-21
[80] Plutarch, “Themistokles”, 4.9-10
[81] Rhodes, “Hist”. 6.1, p55
[82] Plutarch, “Kimon”, 10
[83] Burn, “Hist”. chp.9.4, p210
[84] Buckley, “Aspects”. P217
[85] Plutarch, “Themistokles”, 19.27-30
[86] Thucydides, “Hist”. 1.109-111
[87] Plutarch, “Themistokles”, 19.27-30
[88] Hammond “Hist”. chp.5.4 p263
[89] Aeschylos, “Eumenides”  lines 560-578
[90] Meiggs, “Hist”. chp.9.1, p216
[91] Plutarch, “Kimon”, 16.59-61
[92] Herodotus”, “Histories” VII.9
[93] Herodotus”, “Histories” VII.9
 
 
Fin!
Back to Top
Vorian View Drop Down
Colonel
Colonel
Avatar

Joined: 06-Dec-2007
Location: Greece/Hellas
Online Status: Offline
Posts: 566
  Quote Vorian Quote  Post ReplyReply Direct Link To This Post Posted: 15-May-2009 at 20:11
Wow. Bookmarked to read it later, this deserves careful reading
Back to Top
Flipper View Drop Down
Arch Duke
Arch Duke
Avatar

Joined: 23-Apr-2006
Location: Flipper HQ
Online Status: Offline
Posts: 1813
  Quote Flipper Quote  Post ReplyReply Direct Link To This Post Posted: 15-May-2009 at 20:44
Bravo!
And it came on right time. It's on the weekends i spend my time drinking coffee and reading posts on AE. Smile


Så nu tar jag fram (k)niven va!
Back to Top
bod View Drop Down
Janissary
Janissary
Avatar

Joined: 25-Apr-2009
Location: England
Online Status: Offline
Posts: 24
  Quote bod Quote  Post ReplyReply Direct Link To This Post Posted: 15-May-2009 at 21:10
This looks great. I'm just reading my first book on Greece and I'm sure this will add to my enjoyment and understanding of the subject.

will print it out now.....

ThankyouStar


Back to Top
eaglecap View Drop Down
Tsar
Tsar
Avatar
Retired AE Moderator

Joined: 15-Feb-2005
Location: ArizonaUSA
Online Status: Offline
Posts: 3959
  Quote eaglecap Quote  Post ReplyReply Direct Link To This Post Posted: 19-May-2009 at 22:52
Aster Thrax Eupator - can I copy- paste and print this so I can read it at home? just pm me eaglecap
Λοιπόν, αδελφοί και οι συμπολίτες και οι στρατιώτες, να θυμάστε αυτό ώστε μνημόσυνο σας, φήμη και ελευθερία σας θα ε
Back to Top
Vorian View Drop Down
Colonel
Colonel
Avatar

Joined: 06-Dec-2007
Location: Greece/Hellas
Online Status: Offline
Posts: 566
  Quote Vorian Quote  Post ReplyReply Direct Link To This Post Posted: 20-May-2009 at 12:38
Just read it. A great article must have taken you quite some time
Back to Top
 Post Reply Post Reply

Forum Jump Forum Permissions View Drop Down

Bulletin Board Software by Web Wiz Forums® version 9.56a [Free Express Edition]
Copyright ©2001-2009 Web Wiz

This page was generated in 0.109 seconds.